6
edits
(add info) |
(robot: Update article (please report if you notice any mistake or error in this edit)) |
||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
{{ | {{Short description|Rivalry where multiple parties strive for a goal which cannot be shared}} | ||
{{Other uses|Competition (disambiguation)|Compete (disambiguation)}} | |||
[[File:Athletics competitions.jpg|thumb|right|300px|Competition in sports. One selection of images showing some of the sporting events that are classed as [[sport of athletics|athletics]] competitions.]] | |||
'''Competition''' is a [[rivalry]] where two or more parties strive for a common [[goal]] which cannot be shared: where one's gain is the other's loss (an example of which is a [[zero-sum game]]).<ref>Smith, K.G., Ferrier, W.J. and Ndofor, H., 2001. Competitive dynamics research: Critique and future directions. Handbook of strategic management, pp.315-361.</ref> Competition can arise between entities such as organisms, individuals, economic and social groups, etc. The rivalry can be over attainment of any exclusive goal, including [[Recognition (sociology)|recognition]]: (e.g. [[award]]s, goods, mates, status, prestige), [[leadership]], [[market share]], niches and scarce [[resource]]s, or a [[territory (animal)|territory]]. | |||
Competition occurs in nature, between living organisms which co-exist in the same [[natural environment|environment]]. Animals compete over water supplies, food, mates, and other [[resource (biology)|biological resources]]. [[Human]]s usually [[Survival of the fittest|compete for food and mates]], though when these needs are met deep rivalries often arise over the pursuit of [[wealth]], power, prestige, and [[celebrity|fame]] when in a static, repetitive, or unchanging environment. Competition is a major tenet of [[market economy|market economies]] and business, often associated with business competition as companies are in competition with at least one other firm over the same group of customers. Competition inside a company is usually stimulated with the larger purpose of meeting and reaching higher quality of services or improved products that the company may produce or develop. | |||
Competition is often considered to be the opposite of [[cooperation]], however in the real world, mixtures of cooperation and competition are the norm.<ref>[http://www.sociologyguide.com/basic-concepts/Competition.php Competition], Sociology guide</ref> In economies, as the philosopher R. G. Collingwood argued "the presence of these two opposites together is essential to an economic system. The parties to an economic action co-operate in competing, like two chess players".<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Collingwood|first=Robin, George|date=1926|title=Economics as a Philosophical Science|url=https://www.journals.uchicago.edu/doi/abs/10.1086/intejethi.36.2.2377247?journalCode=intejethi|journal=The International Journal of Ethics|volume=36|issue=2|pages=162–185 at. p. 177|doi=10.1086/intejethi.36.2.2377247|s2cid=143530850}}</ref> Optimal strategies to achieve goals are studied in the branch of mathematics known as [[game theory]]. | |||
Competition has been studied in several fields, including [[psychology]], [[sociology]] and [[anthropology]]. Social [[psychologist]]s, for instance, study the nature of competition. They investigate the natural urge of competition and its circumstances. They also study [[group dynamics]], to detect how competition emerges and what its effects are. [[Sociologist]]s, meanwhile, study the effects of competition on society as a whole. Additionally, [[anthropologist]]s study the [[history]] and prehistory of competition in various cultures. They also investigate how competition manifested itself in various [[culture|cultural]] settings in the past, and how competition has developed over time. | |||
== Biology and ecology == | == Biology and ecology == | ||
Line 11: | Line 17: | ||
Competition within, between, and among species is one of the most important forces in biology, especially in the field of [[ecology]].<ref name="Keddy, P.A 2001">Keddy, P.A. '''2001'''. ''Competition'', 2nd ed., Kluwer, Dordrecht. 552 p.</ref> | Competition within, between, and among species is one of the most important forces in biology, especially in the field of [[ecology]].<ref name="Keddy, P.A 2001">Keddy, P.A. '''2001'''. ''Competition'', 2nd ed., Kluwer, Dordrecht. 552 p.</ref> | ||
Competition between members of a species ("intraspecific") for resources such as [[food]], [[water]], [[Territory (animal)|territory]], and [[sunlight]] may result in an increase in the frequency of a variant of the species best suited for survival and reproduction until its fixation within a population. However, competition among resources also has a strong tendency for diversification between members of the same species, resulting in coexistence of competitive and non-competitive strategies or cycles between low and high competitiveness. Third parties within a species often favour highly competitive strategies leading to species extinction when environmental conditions are harsh ([[evolutionary suicide]]).<ref>{{cite journal|last1=Baldauf|first1=Sebastian A.|last2=Engqvist|first2=Leif|last3=Weissing|first3=Franz J.|title=Diversifying evolution of competitiveness|journal=Nature Communications|date=29 October 2014|volume=5|pages=5233|doi=10.1038/ncomms6233|pmid=25351604|bibcode=2014NatCo...5.5233B| | Competition between members of a species ("intraspecific") for resources such as [[food]], [[water]], [[Territory (animal)|territory]], and [[sunlight]] may result in an increase in the frequency of a variant of the species best suited for survival and reproduction until its fixation within a population. However, competition among resources also has a strong tendency for diversification between members of the same species, resulting in coexistence of competitive and non-competitive strategies or cycles between low and high competitiveness. Third parties within a species often favour highly competitive strategies leading to species extinction when environmental conditions are harsh ([[evolutionary suicide]]).<ref>{{cite journal|last1=Baldauf|first1=Sebastian A.|last2=Engqvist|first2=Leif|last3=Weissing|first3=Franz J.|title=Diversifying evolution of competitiveness|journal=Nature Communications|date=29 October 2014|volume=5|pages=5233|doi=10.1038/ncomms6233|pmid=25351604|bibcode=2014NatCo...5.5233B|doi-access=free}}</ref> | ||
Competition is also present between species ("interspecific"). When resources are limited, several species may depend on these resources. Thus, each of the species competes with the others to gain access to the resources. As a result, species less suited to compete for the resources may [[extinction|die out]] unless they [[adaptation|adapt]] by character dislocation, for instance. According to [[evolutionary theory]], this competition within and between species for resources plays a significant role in [[natural selection]]. At shorter time scales, competition is also one of the most important factors controlling diversity in ecological communities, but at larger scales expansion and contraction of ecological space is a much more larger factor than competition.<ref name="SahneyBentonFerry2010">{{cite journal|author1=Sahney, S. |author2=Benton, M.J. |author3=Ferry, P.A.|year=2010|title=Links between global taxonomic diversity, ecological diversity and the expansion of vertebrates on land|journal=Biology Letters|volume=6|issue=4|pages=544–47|doi=10.1098/rsbl.2009.1024|pmc=2936204|pmid=20106856}}</ref> This is illustrated by living plant communities where asymmetric competition and competitive dominance frequently occur.<ref name="Keddy, P.A 2001" /> Multiple examples of symmetric and asymmetric competition also exist for animals.<ref>{{cite journal|last1=Borzée|first1=Amaël|last2=Kim|first2=Jun Young|last3=Jang|first3=Yikweon|title=Asymmetric competition over calling sites in two closely related treefrog species|journal=Scientific Reports|date=7 Sep 2016|volume=6|page=32569|doi=10.1038/srep32569|pmc=5013533|pmid=27599461|bibcode=2016NatSR...632569B}}</ref> | Competition is also present between species ("interspecific"). When resources are limited, several species may depend on these resources. Thus, each of the species competes with the others to gain access to the resources. As a result, species less suited to compete for the resources may [[extinction|die out]] unless they [[adaptation|adapt]] by character dislocation, for instance. According to [[evolutionary theory]], this competition within and between species for resources plays a significant role in [[natural selection]]. At shorter time scales, competition is also one of the most important factors controlling diversity in ecological communities, but at larger scales expansion and contraction of ecological space is a much more larger factor than competition.<ref name="SahneyBentonFerry2010">{{cite journal|author1=Sahney, S. |author2=Benton, M.J. |author3=Ferry, P.A.|year=2010|title=Links between global taxonomic diversity, ecological diversity and the expansion of vertebrates on land|journal=Biology Letters|volume=6|issue=4|pages=544–47|doi=10.1098/rsbl.2009.1024|pmc=2936204|pmid=20106856}}</ref> This is illustrated by living plant communities where asymmetric competition and competitive dominance frequently occur.<ref name="Keddy, P.A 2001" /> Multiple examples of symmetric and asymmetric competition also exist for animals.<ref>{{cite journal|last1=Borzée|first1=Amaël|last2=Kim|first2=Jun Young|last3=Jang|first3=Yikweon|title=Asymmetric competition over calling sites in two closely related treefrog species|journal=Scientific Reports|date=7 Sep 2016|volume=6|page=32569|doi=10.1038/srep32569|pmc=5013533|pmid=27599461|bibcode=2016NatSR...632569B}}</ref> | ||
== Consumer competitions - games of luck or skill == | == Consumer competitions - games of luck or skill == | ||
Line 26: | Line 31: | ||
Such competitions can be games of luck (randomly drawn) or skill (judged on an entry question or submission), or possibly a combination of both. | Such competitions can be games of luck (randomly drawn) or skill (judged on an entry question or submission), or possibly a combination of both. | ||
People that enjoy entering competitions are known as compers. Many compers attend annual national conventions. In 2012 over 100 members of the online competitions community of lottos.com.au from around Australia met on the Gold Coast, Queensland to discuss competitions.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.lottos.com.au/competitions/viewthreadlite.php?tid=275933|title=NATIONAL LOTTOS MEET GOLD COAST 16TH SEPTEMBER 2012 :)|publisher=Lottos.com.au|access-date=2013-08-02|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130724001800/http://www.lottos.com.au/competitions/viewthreadlite.php?tid=275933|archive-date=2013-07-24|url-status=dead}}</ref><ref>{{cite web|url=https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=amv7jMwbHIw&t=6s|title=Comp Queens|date=2012-09-21|publisher=Aca.ninemsn.com.au|access-date=2013-08-02}}</ref> | People that enjoy entering competitions are known as compers. Many compers attend annual national conventions. In 2012 over 100 members of the online competitions community of lottos.com.au from around Australia met on the Gold Coast, Queensland to discuss competitions.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.lottos.com.au/competitions/viewthreadlite.php?tid=275933|title=NATIONAL LOTTOS MEET GOLD COAST 16TH SEPTEMBER 2012 :)|publisher=Lottos.com.au|access-date=2013-08-02|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130724001800/http://www.lottos.com.au/competitions/viewthreadlite.php?tid=275933|archive-date=2013-07-24|url-status=dead}}</ref><ref>Archived at [https://ghostarchive.org/varchive/youtube/20211211/amv7jMwbHIw Ghostarchive]{{cbignore}} and the [https://web.archive.org/web/20191003092409/https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=amv7jMwbHIw&gl=US&hl=en Wayback Machine]{{cbignore}}: {{cite web|url=https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=amv7jMwbHIw&t=6s|title=Comp Queens|date=2012-09-21|publisher=Aca.ninemsn.com.au|access-date=2013-08-02}}{{cbignore}}</ref> | ||
==Competitiveness== | ==Competitiveness== | ||
Line 35: | Line 40: | ||
== Education == | == Education == | ||
Competition is a major factor in education. On a global scale, national education systems, intending to bring out the best in the next generation, encourage competitiveness among students through [[scholarships]]. Countries such as England and Singapore have [[special education]] programmes which cater for specialist students, prompting charges of [[academic elitism]]. Upon receipt of their academic results, students tend to compare their grades to see who is better. In severe cases, the pressure to perform in some countries is so high that it can result in stigmatization of intellectually deficient students, or even suicide as a consequence of failing the exams; Japan being a prime example (see [[Education in Japan]]).This has resulted in critical re-evaluation of examinations as a whole by educationalists {{Citation needed|date=February 2007}}. Critics of competition as a motivating factor in education systems, such as [[Alfie Kohn]], assert that competition actually has a net negative influence on the achievement levels of students, and that it "turns all of us into losers" (Kohn 1986). Economist [[Richard Layard]] has commented on the harmful effects, stating "people feel that they are under a great deal of pressure. They feel that their main objective in life is to do better than other people. That is certainly what young people are being taught in school every day. And it's not a good basis for a society."<ref>[https://www.bbc.co.uk/news/uk-13052639 ''Group dedicated to happiness launched in UK'', BBC video, April 12, 2011]</ref> | {{Main|Competition-based learning}} | ||
Competition is a major factor in education. On a global scale, national education systems, intending to bring out the best in the next generation, encourage competitiveness among students through [[scholarships]]. Countries such as England and Singapore have [[special education]] programmes which cater for specialist students, prompting charges of [[academic elitism]]. Upon receipt of their academic results, students tend to compare their grades to see who is better. In severe cases, the pressure to perform in some countries is so high that it can result in stigmatization of intellectually deficient students, or even suicide as a consequence of failing the exams; Japan being a prime example (see [[Education in Japan]]). This has resulted in critical re-evaluation of examinations as a whole by educationalists {{Citation needed|date=February 2007}}. Critics of competition as a motivating factor in education systems, such as [[Alfie Kohn]], assert that competition actually has a net negative influence on the achievement levels of students, and that it "turns all of us into losers" (Kohn 1986). Economist [[Richard Layard]] has commented on the harmful effects, stating "people feel that they are under a great deal of pressure. They feel that their main objective in life is to do better than other people. That is certainly what young people are being taught in school every day. And it's not a good basis for a society."<ref>[https://www.bbc.co.uk/news/uk-13052639 ''Group dedicated to happiness launched in UK'', BBC video, April 12, 2011]</ref> | |||
However, other studies such as the [[Torrance Tests of Creative Thinking]] show that the effect of competition on students depends on each individual's level of [[Agency (philosophy)|agency]]. Students with a high level of agency thrive on competition, are self-motivated, and are willing to risk failure.Compared to their counterparts who are low in agency, these students are more likely to be flexible, adaptable and creative as adults.<ref>{{Citation|last1=Conti|first1=Regina|title=The impact of competition on intrinsic motivation and creativity: Considering gender, gender segregation and gender role orientation|date=December 2001|url=https://www.researchgate.net/publication/223760263|journal=Personality and Individual Differences|volume=31|issue=8|pages=1273–1289|doi=10.1016/S0191-8869(00)00217-8|last2=Picariello|first2=Martha|last3=Collins|first3=Mary}}</ref><ref>{{Citation|last1=Eisenberg|first1=Jacob|title=The Effects of Competition on Improvisers' Motivation, Stress, and Creative Performance|date=16 April 2012|journal=Creativity Research Journal|volume=23|issue=2|pages=129–136|doi=10.1080/10400419.2011.571185|issn=1040-0419|last2=Thompson|first2=William Forde|s2cid=144893872}}</ref> | However, other studies such as the [[Torrance Tests of Creative Thinking]] show that the effect of competition on students depends on each individual's level of [[Agency (philosophy)|agency]]. Students with a high level of agency thrive on competition, are self-motivated, and are willing to risk failure. Compared to their counterparts who are low in agency, these students are more likely to be flexible, adaptable and creative as adults.<ref>{{Citation|last1=Conti|first1=Regina|title=The impact of competition on intrinsic motivation and creativity: Considering gender, gender segregation and gender role orientation|date=December 2001|url=https://www.researchgate.net/publication/223760263|journal=Personality and Individual Differences|volume=31|issue=8|pages=1273–1289|doi=10.1016/S0191-8869(00)00217-8|last2=Picariello|first2=Martha|last3=Collins|first3=Mary}}</ref><ref>{{Citation|last1=Eisenberg|first1=Jacob|title=The Effects of Competition on Improvisers' Motivation, Stress, and Creative Performance|date=16 April 2012|journal=Creativity Research Journal|volume=23|issue=2|pages=129–136|doi=10.1080/10400419.2011.571185|issn=1040-0419|last2=Thompson|first2=William Forde|s2cid=144893872}}</ref> | ||
==Economics== | ==Economics== | ||
{{Main|Competition (economics)}} | {{Main|Competition (economics)}} | ||
Merriam-Webster gives as one definition of competition (relating to [[business sector|business]]) as "[...] rivalry: such as [...] the effort of two or more parties acting independently to secure the business of a third party by offering the most favorable terms".<ref>Compare: [http://m-w.com/dictionary/competition Definition of competition] - "competition [...] 1 : the act or process of competing : rivalry: such as [...] a : the effort of two or more parties acting independently to secure the business of a third party by offering the most favorable terms "</ref> [[Adam Smith]] in his 1776 book ''[[The Wealth of Nations]]'' and later economists described competition in general as allocating productive [[resource]]s to their most highly valued uses and encouraging [[X-inefficiency|efficiency]].<ref>[[George J. Stigler]] ([[The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics|[1987]]] 2008). "competition," ''[[The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics]]''. [http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_C000261&q=competition&topicid=&result_number=6 Abstract.] | Merriam-Webster gives as one definition of competition (relating to [[business sector|business]]) as "[...] rivalry: such as [...] the effort of two or more parties acting independently to secure the business of a third party by offering the most favorable terms".<ref>Compare: [http://m-w.com/dictionary/competition Definition of competition] - "competition [...] 1 : the act or process of competing : rivalry: such as [...] a : the effort of two or more parties acting independently to secure the business of a third party by offering the most favorable terms "</ref> [[Adam Smith]] in his 1776 book ''[[The Wealth of Nations]]'' and later economists described competition in general as allocating productive [[resource]]s to their most highly valued uses and encouraging [[X-inefficiency|efficiency]].<ref>[[George J. Stigler]] ([[The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics|[1987]]] 2008). "competition," ''[[The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics]]''. [http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_C000261&q=competition&topicid=&result_number=6 Abstract.] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150215032134/http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_C000261&q=competition&topicid=&result_number=6 |date=2015-02-15 }}</ref>{{qn|date=March 2020}} Later [[microeconomic theory]] distinguished between [[perfect competition]] and [[imperfect competition]], concluding that no system of resource allocation is more efficient than [[perfect competition]].{{citation needed|date=March 2020}} Competition, according to the theory, causes commercial firms to develop new products, services and technologies, which would give consumers greater selection and better products. The greater selection typically causes lower prices for the products, compared to what the price would be if there was no competition ([[monopoly]]) or little competition ([[oligopoly]]).{{citation needed|date=March 2020}} | ||
{{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150215032134/http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_C000261&q=competition&topicid=&result_number=6 |date=2015-02-15 }}</ref>{{qn|date=March 2020}} Later [[microeconomic theory]] distinguished between [[perfect competition]] and [[imperfect competition]], concluding that no system of resource allocation is more efficient than [[perfect competition]].{{citation needed|date=March 2020}} Competition, according to the theory, causes commercial firms to develop new products, services and technologies, which would give consumers greater selection and better products. The greater selection typically causes lower prices for the products, compared to what the price would be if there was no competition ([[monopoly]]) or little competition ([[oligopoly]]).{{citation needed|date=March 2020}} | |||
However, competition may also lead to wasted (duplicated) effort and to increased [[cost]]s (and prices) in some circumstances. For example, the intense competition for the small number of [[superstar|top jobs in music and movie-acting]] leads many aspiring musicians and actors to make substantial investments in training which are not recouped, because only a fraction become successful. Critics{{which|date=March 2020}} have also argued that competition can be destabilizing, particularly competition between certain financial institutions. | However, competition may also lead to wasted (duplicated) effort and to increased [[cost]]s (and prices) in some circumstances. For example, the intense competition for the small number of [[superstar|top jobs in music and movie-acting]] leads many aspiring musicians and actors to make substantial investments in training which are not recouped, because only a fraction become successful. Critics{{which|date=March 2020}} have also argued that competition can be destabilizing, particularly competition between certain financial institutions. | ||
Experts have also questioned the constructiveness of competition in profitability. It has been argued that competition-oriented objectives are counterproductive to raising revenues and profitability because they limit the options of strategies for firms as well as their ability to offer innovative responses to changes in the market.<ref>{{cite journal |url= http://marketing.wharton.upenn.edu/documents/research/CompOrientPDF%2011-27%20%282%29.pdf |title= The Profitability of Winning |author1= J. Scott Armstrong |author2= Fred Collopy |journal= Chief Executive |pages= 61–63 |year= 1994 |access-date= 2011-12-06 |archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20100622023252/http://marketing.wharton.upenn.edu/documents/research/CompOrientPDF%2011-27%20(2).pdf |archive-date= 2010-06-22 |url-status= dead | quote = A 1996 review of the evidence, summarized in this paper, found that competitor-oriented objectives reduced profitability.We describe new evidence from 12 studies, one of which is introduced in this paper. The new evidence supports the conclusion that competitor-oriented objectives are harmful, especially when managers receive information about competitors' market shares.}}</ref> In addition, the strong desire to defeat rival firms with competitive prices has the strong possibility of causing [[price war]]s.<ref>{{cite journal | url = http://qbox.wharton.upenn.edu/documents/mktg/research/Profitability%20of%20winning.pdf | title = Competitor-oriented Objectives: The Myth of Market Share | author1 = J. Scott Armstrong | author2 = Kesten C. Greene | journal = International Journal of Business | volume = 12 | issue = 1 | pages = 116–34 | year = 2007 | issn = 1083-4346 }}{{Dead link|date= November 2019 |bot= InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted= yes }}</ref> | Experts have also questioned the constructiveness of competition in profitability. It has been argued that competition-oriented objectives are counterproductive to raising revenues and profitability because they limit the options of strategies for firms as well as their ability to offer innovative responses to changes in the market.<ref>{{cite journal |url= http://marketing.wharton.upenn.edu/documents/research/CompOrientPDF%2011-27%20%282%29.pdf |title= The Profitability of Winning |author1= J. Scott Armstrong |author2= Fred Collopy |journal= Chief Executive |pages= 61–63 |year= 1994 |access-date= 2011-12-06 |archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20100622023252/http://marketing.wharton.upenn.edu/documents/research/CompOrientPDF%2011-27%20(2).pdf |archive-date= 2010-06-22 |url-status= dead | quote = A 1996 review of the evidence, summarized in this paper, found that competitor-oriented objectives reduced profitability. We describe new evidence from 12 studies, one of which is introduced in this paper. The new evidence supports the conclusion that competitor-oriented objectives are harmful, especially when managers receive information about competitors' market shares.}}</ref> In addition, the strong desire to defeat rival firms with competitive prices has the strong possibility of causing [[price war]]s.<ref>{{cite journal | url = http://qbox.wharton.upenn.edu/documents/mktg/research/Profitability%20of%20winning.pdf | title = Competitor-oriented Objectives: The Myth of Market Share | author1 = J. Scott Armstrong | author2 = Kesten C. Greene | journal = International Journal of Business | volume = 12 | issue = 1 | pages = 116–34 | year = 2007 | issn = 1083-4346 }}{{Dead link|date= November 2019 |bot= InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted= yes }}</ref> | ||
Another distinction appearing in economics is that between competition as an end-state – as in the case of both perfect and imperfect competition – and competition as a ''process.'' That process is typically seen as a process. It is a process of rivalry between firms (or consumers) intensifying selective pressures for improvements. One can restate this as a process of discovery.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Blaug|first=Mark|title=Is Competition Such a Good Thing? Static Efficiency versus Dynamic Efficiency|date=2001|url=http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/a:1011160622792|journal=Review of Industrial Organization|volume=19|issue=1|pages=37–48|doi=10.1023/a:1011160622792|s2cid=154441911|issn=0889-938X}}</ref> | |||
Three levels of end-state economic competition have been classified:{{by whom|date=March 2020}} | |||
* The most narrow form is '''direct competition''' (also called "category competition" or "brand competition"), where [[product (business)|products]] which perform the same function compete against each other. For example, one brand of pick-up trucks competes with several other brands of pick-up trucks. Sometimes, two companies are rivals and one adds new products to their line, which leads to the other company distributing the same new things, and in this manner they compete. | |||
* The next form is '''substitute''' or '''indirect competition''', where products which are close substitutes for one another compete. For example, butter competes with margarine, with mayonnaise and with other various sauces and spreads. | |||
* The broadest form of competition is typically called '''budget competition'''. Included in this category is anything on which the [[consumer]] might want to spend their available [[income|money]]. For example, a family which has $20,000 available may choose to spend it on many different items, which can all be seen as competing with each other for the family's expenditure. This form of competition is also sometimes described as a competition of "share of wallet". | |||
In addition, companies compete for [[finance|financing]] on the capital markets (equity or debt) in order to generate the necessary cash for their operations. [[Investor]] typically consider alternative investment opportunities given their risk profile, and not only look at companies just competing on product ('''direct competitors'''). Enlarging the investment universe to include '''indirect competitors''' leads to a broader peer universe of comparable, indirectly competing companies. | |||
Competition does not necessarily have to be between companies. For example, [[business writer]]s sometimes refer to '''internal competition'''. This is competition within companies. The idea was first introduced by [[Alfred Sloan]] at [[General Motors Corporation|General Motors]] in the 1920s. Sloan deliberately created areas of overlap between [[Division (organization)|division]]s of the company so that each division would compete with the other divisions. For example, the [[Chevrolet]] division would compete with the [[Pontiac (automobile)|Pontiac]] division for some [[market segment]]s. The competing brands by the same company allowed parts to be designed by one division and shared by several divisions, for example parts designed by Chevrolet would also be used by Pontiac. In 1931 [[Procter & Gamble]] initiated a deliberate system of internal brand-versus-brand rivalry. The company was organized{{by whom|date=March 2020}} around different [[brand]]s, with each brand allocated resources, including a dedicated group of employees willing to champion the brand. Each [[brand manager]] was given responsibility for the success or failure of the brand, and compensated accordingly. | |||
Most businesses also encourage competition between individual employees. An example of this is a contest between sales representatives. The sales representative with the highest sales (or the best improvement in sales) over a period of time would gain benefits from the employer. This is also known as '''intra-brand competition'''. | |||
Shalev and Asbjornsen found that success (i.e. the saving resulted) of [[reverse auction]]s correlated most closely with competition. The literature widely supported the importance of competition as the primary driver of reverse auctions success.<ref>[https://ssrn.com/abstract=1727409 papers.ssrn.com]</ref> Their findings appear to support that argument, as competition correlated strongly with the reverse auction success, as well as with the number of bidders.<ref>{{cite web |url= https://www.scribd.com/doc/39032383/Electronic-Reverse-Auction-and-the-Public-Sector-Factors-of-Success-Moshe-E-Shalev-Stee-Asbjorensen | publisher= Shalev Moshe and Asbjornsen Stee |title= Electronic reverse auctions and the public sector – Factors of success |work= Journal of Public Procurement |pages= 428–52 |volume=10 |issue= 3}}</ref> | |||
Business and economic competition in most [[country|countries]] is often{{quantify|date=March 2020}} limited or restricted. Competition often is subject to legal restrictions. For example, competition may be legally prohibited, as in the cases of a [[government monopoly]] or of a [[government-granted monopoly]]. Governments may institute [[tariffs]], [[subsidies]] or other [[protectionist]] measures in order to prevent or reduce competition. Depending on the respective economic policy, pure competition is to a greater or lesser extent regulated by [[competition policy]] and [[competition law]]. Another component of these activities is the [[discovery process]], with instances of higher [[government regulation]]s typically leading to less competitive businesses being launched.<ref>[http://www.cato.org/pub_display.php?pub_id=884&full=1 Competition, Regulation, and the Market Process: An "Austrian" Perspective, Sept. 30, 1982] by [[Israel M. Kirzner]]</ref> | |||
Nicholas Gruen has referred to ''The Competition Delusion'',<ref>[https://www.griffithreview.com/articles/trust-competition-delusion-gruen/ The Competition Delusion]</ref> in which competition is taken to be unambiguously good, even where that competition leaks into the rules of the game. He claims this drives financialisation (the approximate doubling of proportion of economic resources dedicated to finance and to 'rule making and administering' professions such as law, accountancy and auditing. | |||
===Interstate=== | |||
{{See also| Race to the bottom}} | |||
Competition between countries is quite subtle to detect, but is quite evident in the [[world economy]].{{citation needed|date=March 2020}} Countries compete to provide the best possible [[commerce|business]] environment for [[multinational corporations]]. Such competition is evident by the policies undertaken by these countries to educate the future workforce. For example, East Asian economies such as Singapore, Japan and South Korea tend to compete by allocating a large portion of the budget to the education sector, including by implementing programmes such as [[gifted education]]. | |||
===Law=== | |||
{{Main|Competition law}} | |||
[[File:U.S. Department of Justice headquarters, August 12, 2006.jpg|thumb|right |The [[United States Department of Justice|Department of Justice]] building in [[Washington, D.C.]] houses the influential [[United States antitrust law|antitrust]] enforcers of U.S. competition laws]] | |||
Competition [[law]], known in the [[United States]] as antitrust law, has three main functions: | |||
* First, it prohibits agreements aimed to restrict free trading between business entities and their customers. For example, a [[cartel]] of sports shops who together fix football-jersey prices higher than normal is illegal.<ref>''JJB Sports v OFT [2004] CAT 17''</ref> | |||
* Second, competition law can ban the existence or abusive behaviour of a firm dominating the market. One case in point could be a software company who through its [[monopoly]] on computer platforms makes consumers use its media player.<ref>In the E.U. side of the saga, see [https://curia.europa.eu/jcms/upload/docs/application/pdf/2009-02/cp070063en.pdf Case T-201/04] <br/>{{Webarchive|url= https://web.archive.org/web/20220210183724/https://curia.europa.eu/jcms/upload/docs/application/pdf/2009-02/cp070063en.pdf |date= 2022-02-10 }} ''Microsoft v. Commission'' Order, [revised] 17 September 2007</ref> | |||
* Third, to preserve competitive markets, the law supervises the [[mergers and acquisitions]] of very large corporations. Competition authorities could for instance require that a large packaging company give plastic bottle [[license]]s to competitors before taking over a major [[Polyethylene terephthalate|PET]] producer.<ref>Case C-12/03 P, Commission v. Tetra Laval</ref> | |||
In all three cases, competition law aims to protect the [[consumer welfare|welfare of consumers]] by ensuring that each business must compete for its share of the [[market economy]]. | |||
In recent decades,{{when|date=March 2020}} competition law has also been sold{{by whom|date=March 2020}} as good medicine to provide better [[public services]], traditionally funded by [[tax]]-payers and administered by [[Democracy|democratically]] accountable{{clarify|date=March 2020}} [[government]]s. Hence competition law is closely connected with the law on deregulation of access to markets, providing state aids and subsidies, the [[privatisation]] of state-owned assets and the use of independent sector regulators, such as the United Kingdom telecommunications watchdog [[Ofcom]]. Behind the practice lies the theory, which over the last fifty years{{when|date=March 2020}} has been dominated by [[neo-classical economics]]. Markets are seen as the most efficient method of allocating resources, although sometimes [[market failure|they fail]], and regulation becomes necessary to protect the ideal market model. Behind the theory lies the history, reaching back further than the [[Roman Empire]]. The business practices of market traders, [[guilds]] and governments have always been subject to scrutiny and sometimes to severe sanctions. Since the twentieth century, competition law has become global.{{citation needed|date=March 2020}} The two largest, most organised and influential systems of competition regulation are [[United States antitrust law]] and [[European Community competition law]]. The respective national/international authorities, the [[U.S. Department of Justice]] (DOJ) and the [[Federal Trade Commission]] (FTC) in the United States and the [[Directorate-General for Competition (European Commission)|European Commission's Competition Directorate General]] (DGCOMP) have formed international support- and enforcement-networks. Competition law is growing in importance every day,{{citation needed|date=March 2020}} which warrants for its careful study. | |||
==Game theory== | |||
{{main|Game theory}} | |||
Game theory is "the study of [[mathematical model]]s of conflict and cooperation between intelligent rational decision-makers."<ref name="Myerson">[[Roger B. Myerson|Myerson, Roger B.]] (1991). ''Game Theory: Analysis of Conflict,'' Harvard University Press, p. [https://books.google.com/books?id=E8WQFRCsNr0C&printsec=find&pg=PA1 1]. Chapter-preview links, pp. [https://books.google.com/books?id=E8WQFRCsNr0C&printsec=find&pg=PR7 vii–xi].</ref> Game theory is mainly used in [[economics]], [[political science]], and [[psychology]], as well as [[logic]], [[computer science]], [[biology]] and [[poker]].<ref>{{cite web|url=https://www.wsj.com/articles/SB10001424127887323610704578625812355516182|title=The Science of Winning Poker|author=Christopher Chabris|date=26 July 2013|work=WSJ}}</ref> Originally, it mainly addressed [[zero-sum game]]s, in which one person's gains result in losses for the other participants. | |||
Game theory is a major method used in [[mathematical economics]] and business for [[Economic model|modeling]] competing behaviors of interacting [[Agent (economics)|agent]]s.<ref name="r1" /> Applications include a wide array of economic phenomena and approaches, such as [[auction]]s, [[bargaining]], [[mergers & acquisitions]] pricing,<ref name="GT-A-E-00" /> [[fair division]], [[Duopoly|duopolies]], [[Oligopoly|oligopolies]], [[social network]] formation, [[agent-based computational economics]],<ref name="r2" /> [[general equilibrium]], [[mechanism design]],<ref name="r3" /> and [[voting system]]s;<ref name="r4" /> and across such broad areas as [[experimental economics]],<ref name="r5" /> [[Behavioral game theory|behavioral economics]],<ref name="r6" /> [[information economics]],<ref name="r7" /> [[industrial organization]],<ref name="r8" /> and [[political economy]].<ref name="r9" /><ref name="r10" /> | |||
This research usually focuses on particular sets of strategies known as [[Solution concept|"solution concepts" or "equilibria"]]. A common assumption is that players act rationally. In non-cooperative games, the most famous of these is the [[Nash equilibrium]]. A set of strategies is a Nash equilibrium if each represents a best response to the other strategies. If all the players are playing the strategies in a Nash equilibrium, they have no unilateral incentive to deviate, since their strategy is the best they can do given what others are doing.<ref name="GT-F-R-09">[http://www.insead.edu/facultyresearch/research/doc.cfm?did=46503 Game-theoretic model to examine the two tradeoffs in the acquisition of information for a careful balancing act] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130524231021/http://www.insead.edu/facultyresearch/research/doc.cfm?did=46503|date=2013-05-24}} Research paper [[INSEAD]]</ref><ref name="GT-F-R-10">[http://www.europeanfinancialreview.com/?p=4645 Options Games: Balancing the trade-off between flexibility and commitment] {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130620053305/http://www.europeanfinancialreview.com/?p=4645|date=June 20, 2013}}. Europeanfinancialreview.com (2012-02-15). Retrieved on 2013-01-03.</ref> | |||
== Literature == | |||
Literary competitions, such as contests sponsored by [[literary journals]], publishing houses and theaters, have increasingly become a means for aspiring writers to gain recognition. Awards for fiction include those sponsored by the ''[[Missouri Review]]'', ''[[Boston Review]]'', ''[[Indiana Review]]'', ''[[North American Review]]'' and ''[[Southwest Review]]''. The [[Edward Albee|Albee]] Award, sponsored by the Yale Drama Series, is among the most prestigious playwriting awards.{{Citation needed|date=July 2013}} | |||
==Philosophy== | |||
[[Margaret Heffernan]]'s study, ''A Bigger Prize'',<ref> | |||
{{cite book|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Kc3HAQAAQBAJ|title=A Bigger Prize: Why Competition Isn't Everything and How We Do Better|last1=Heffernan|first1=Margaret|publisher=Simon and Schuster|isbn=9781471100772|location=London|date=2014|author-link1=Margaret Heffernan|access-date=2014-03-16}} | |||
</ref> | |||
examines the perils and disadvantages of competition in (for example) biology, families, sport, education, commerce and the Soviet Union.<ref> | |||
{{cite news|url=https://www.theguardian.com/books/2014/mar/10/bigger-prize-review-competition-margaret-heffernan|title=A Bigger Prize review – the price we pay for competition|last1=Morris|first1=Iain|newspaper=The Guardian|access-date=2014-03-16|publisher=Guardian News and Media Limited|department=Books|date=2014-03-10|edition=UK|issn=0261-3077|quote=Margaret Heffernan's brave study shows how the competitive instinct can be bad for us in all walks of life, from sport to finance}} | |||
</ref> | |||
===Marx=== | |||
[[Karl Marx]] insisted that "the capitalist system fosters competition and egoism in all its members and thoroughly undermines all genuine forms of community".<ref> | |||
{{cite book|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=y2UEAQAAIAAJ|title=Marx and Justice: The Radical Critique of Liberalism|last1=Buchanan|first1=Allen E.|publisher=Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, Incorporated|isbn=9780847670390|series=Philosophy and Society Series|date=1982|page=95|quote=This problem is greatly exacerbated by Marx's insistence that the capitalist system fosters competition and egoism in all its members and thoroughly undermines all genuine forms of community.|author-link1=Allen Buchanan|access-date=2014-03-16}} | |||
</ref> | |||
It promotes a "climate of competitive egoism and individualism", with competition for jobs and competition between employees; Marx said competition between workers exceeds that demonstrated by company owners.<ref name="allenb"> | |||
Allen E. Buchanan, ''[https://books.google.com/books?id=j1AOAAAAQAAJ&lpg=PP1&hl=bg&pg=PP1#v=onepage&q&f=false Marx and justice: the radical critique of liberalism]'', [[Taylor & Francis]], 1982 | |||
</ref> He also points out that competition separates individuals from one another and while concentration of workers and development of better communication alleviate this, they are not a decision.<ref name="allenb" /> | |||
===Freud=== | |||
[[Sigmund Freud]] explained competition as a primal dilemma in which all infants find themselves. The infant competes with other family members for the attention and affection of the parent of the opposite sex or the primary caregiving parent. During this time, a boy develops a deep fear that the father (the son's prime rival) will punish him for these feelings of desire for the mother, by castrating him. Girls develop penis envy towards all males. The girl's envy is rooted in the biologic fact that, without a penis, she cannot sexually possess mother, as the infantile id demands, resultantly, the girl redirects her desire for sexual union upon father in competitive rivalry with her mother. This constellation of feelings is known as [[Oedipus Complex]] (after the Greek Mythology figure who accidentally killed his father and married his mother). This is associated with the [[phallic stage]] of childhood development where intense primal emotions of competitive rivalry with (usually) the parent of the same sex are rampant and create a crisis that must be negotiated successfully for healthy psychological development to proceed. Unresolved Oedipus complex competitiveness issues can lead to lifelong neuroses manifesting in various ways related to an overdetermined relationship to competition. | |||
===Mahatma Gandhi=== | |||
[[Mahatma Gandhi|Gandhi]] speaks of egoistic competition.<ref name="Gandhi"> | |||
Parmeshwari Dayal, [https://books.google.com/books?id=FemHmw5fGQUC&lpg=PP1&hl=bg&pg=PP1#v=onepage&q&f=false Gandhian Theory of Social Reconstruction], Atlantic Publishers & Dist, 2006</ref> For him, such qualities glorified and/or left unbridled, can lead to violence, conflict, discord and destructiveness. For Gandhi, competition comes from the ego, and therefore society must be based on mutual love, cooperation and sacrifice for the well-being of humanity.<ref name="Gandhi" /> In the society desired by Gandhi, each individual will cooperate and serve for the welfare of others and people will share each other's joys, sorrows and achievements as a norm of a social life. For him, in a non-violent society, competition does not have a place and this should become realized with more people making the personal choice to have fewer tendencies toward egoism and selfishness.<ref name="Gandhi" /> | |||
== Politics == | |||
Competition is also found in [[politics]]. In [[democracy|democracies]], an [[election]] is a competition for an elected office. In other words, two or more candidates strive and compete against one another to attain a position of power. The winner gains the seat of the elected office for a predefined period of time, towards the end of which another election is usually held to determine the next holder of the office. | |||
In addition, there is inevitable competition inside a government. Because several offices are appointed, potential candidates compete against the others in order to gain the particular office. Departments may also compete for a limited amount of resources, such as for [[budget|funding]]. Finally, where there are [[party systems]], elected leaders of different parties will ultimately compete against the other parties for [[law]]s, [[funding]] and [[political power|power]]. | |||
Finally, competition also exists between [[government]]s. Each [[country]] or [[nationality]] struggles for world dominance, power, or [[military]] strength. For example, the [[United States]] competed against the [[Soviet Union]] in the [[Cold War]] for world power, and the two also struggled over the different types of government (in these cases [[representative democracy]] and [[communism]]). The result of this type of competition often leads to worldwide tensions, and may sometimes erupt into [[war]]fare. | |||
== Sports == | |||
{{Anchor|Competitive sports}}<!-- Previous title. 2013-07-01 --> | |||
[[File:US Olympic Committee Headquarters by David Shankbone.jpg|thumb|upright=1.3|The [[United States Olympic Committee]]'s headquarters in [[Colorado Springs, Colorado]]. The [[Olympic Games]] are regarded as the international pinnacle of sports competition.]] | |||
While some [[sport]]s and [[game]]s (such as [[fishing]] or [[hiking]]) have been viewed as primarily recreational, most sports are considered competitive. The majority involve competition between two or more persons (sometimes using [[horse racing|horses]] or [[auto racing|cars]]). For example, in a game of [[basketball]], two teams compete against one another to determine who can score the most points. When there is no set reward for the winning team, many players gain a sense of [[pride]]. In addition, extrinsic rewards may also be given. Athletes, besides competing against other humans, also compete against [[nature]] in sports such as [[whitewater kayaking]] or [[mountaineering]], where the goal is to reach a destination, with only natural barriers impeding the process. A regularly scheduled (for instance annual) competition meant to determine the "best" competitor of that cycle is called a [[championship]]. | |||
Competitive sports are governed by codified rules agreed upon by the participants. Violating these rules is considered to be [[unfair competition]]. Thus, sports provide artificial (not natural) competition; for example, competing for control of a ball, or defending territory on a playing field is not an innate biological factor in humans. Athletes in sports such as [[gymnastics]] and competitive [[Diving (sport)|diving]] compete against each other in order to come closest to a conceptual ideal of a perfect performance, which incorporates measurable criteria and standards which are translated into numerical ratings and scores by appointed judges. | |||
Sports competition is generally broken down into three categories: '''individual''' sports, such as [[archery]]; '''dual''' sports, such as [[tennis|doubles tennis]], and '''team''' sports competition, such as [[cricket]] or [[football]]. While most sports competitions are recreation, there exist several [[Major professional sports leagues in the United States and Canada|major]] and [[minor league|minor]] professional sports leagues throughout the world. The [[Olympic Games]], held every four years, is usually regarded as the international pinnacle of sports competition. | |||
== Trade == | |||
Competition is also found in [[trade]]. For nations, as well as firms it is important to understand trade dynamics in order to market their goods and services effectively in international markets. [[Balance of trade]] can be considered a crude, but widely used proxy for international competitiveness across levels: [[country]], [[Industry (economics)|industry]] or even [[business|firm]]. Research data hints that exporting firms have a higher survival rate and achieve greater employment growth compared with non-exporters. | |||
Using a simple concept to measure heights that firms can climb may help improve execution of strategies. International competitiveness can be measured on several criteria but few are as flexible and versatile to be applied across levels as Trade Competitiveness Index (TCI) <ref>{{cite journal|author1=Manthri P.|author2=Bhokray K.|author3=Momaya K. S.|year=2015|title=Export Competitiveness of Select Firms from India: Glimpse of Trends and Implications|url=https://kmomaya.files.wordpress.com/2015/05/ijm_pranusha_bhokray_momaya_export_competitiveness_pre-publication_review.pdf|journal=Indian Journal of Marketing|volume=45|issue=5|pages=7–13|doi=10.17010/ijom/2015/v45/i5/79934|access-date=2015-05-28|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160304210603/https://kmomaya.files.wordpress.com/2015/05/ijm_pranusha_bhokray_momaya_export_competitiveness_pre-publication_review.pdf|archive-date=2016-03-04|url-status=dead}}</ref> | |||
=== Hypercompetitiveness === | |||
The tendency toward extreme, unhealthy competition has been termed '''hypercompetitiveness'''. This concept originated in [[Karen Horney]]'s theories on [[neurosis]]; specifically, the highly aggressive personality type which is characterized as "moving against people". In her view, some people have a need to compete and win at all costs as a means of maintaining their [[self-esteem|self-worth]]. These individuals are likely to turn any activity into a competition, and they will feel threatened if they find themselves losing. Researchers have found that men and women who score high on the trait of hypercompetitiveness are more [[Narcissism|narcissistic]] and less psychologically healthy than those who score low on the trait.<ref>{{cite journal |author1=Ryckman, R. M. |author2=Thornton, B. |author3=Butler, J. C. |year=1994 |title= Personality correlates of the hypercompetitive attitude scale: Validity tests of Horney's theory of neurosis |journal=[[Journal of Personality Assessment]]|volume=62 |issue=1 |pages=84–94 |doi=10.1207/s15327752jpa6201_8 |pmid=8138889 }}</ref> Hypercompetitive individuals generally believe that winning is the only thing that matters.<ref>{{cite web |title=Competition freaks |url=https://www.latimes.com/archives/la-xpm-2005-nov-28-he-competition28-story.html |website=Los Angeles Times |access-date=2 February 2021 |date=28 November 2005}}</ref> | |||
== Consequences == | |||
Competition can have both beneficial and detrimental effects. Many evolutionary biologists view inter-species and intra-species competition as the driving force of [[adaptation]], and ultimately of [[evolution]]. However, some biologists disagree, citing competition as a driving force only on a small scale, and citing the larger scale drivers of evolution to be abiotic factors (termed 'Room to Roam').<ref name="SahneyBentonFerry2010" /> [[Richard Dawkins]] prefers to think of evolution in terms of competition between single genes, which have the welfare of the organism 'in mind' only insofar as that welfare furthers their own selfish drives for replication (termed the 'selfish gene'). | |||
Some [[social Darwinist]]s claim that competition also serves as a mechanism for determining the best-suited group; politically, economically and ecologically. Positively, competition may serve as a form of [[recreation]] or a challenge provided that it is non-hostile. On the negative side, competition can cause injury and loss to the organisms involved, and drain valuable resources and energy. In the human species competition can be expensive on many levels, not only in lives lost to war, physical injuries, and damaged psychological well-beings, but also in the health effects from everyday civilian life caused by work stress, long work hours, abusive working relationships, and poor working conditions, that detract from the enjoyment of life, even as such competition results in financial gain for the owners. | |||
== See also == | |||
{{Wiktionary|competition|competitor}} | |||
{{Wikiquote}} | |||
* [[Asymmetric competition]] | |||
* [[Biological interaction]] | |||
* [[Competition regulator]] | |||
* [[Competitor analysis]] | |||
* [[Conflict of interest]] | |||
* [[Cooperation]] | |||
* [[Ecological model of competition]] | |||
* [[Monopolistic competition]] | |||
* [[Non-zero-sum game]] | |||
* [[Win-win game]] | |||
* [[Planned economy]] | |||
* [[Prisoner's dilemma]] | |||
* [[Sharing]] | |||
* [[Student competitions]] | |||
* [[Zero-profit condition]] | |||
* [[Zero-sum]] | |||
== References == | |||
{{Reflist|30em|refs= | |||
<ref name=r1>• At [[JEL classification codes#Mathematical and quantitative methods JEL: C Subcategories|JEL:C7]] of the ''[[Journal of Economic Literature]]'' classification codes.<br /> • [[Robert Aumann|R.J. Aumann]] (2008). "game theory," ''The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics'', 2nd Edition. [http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_G000007&edition=current&q=game%20theory&topicid=&result_number=4 Abstract.]<br /> • [[Martin Shubik]] (1981). "Game Theory Models and Methods in Political Economy," in [[Kenneth Arrow]] and Michael Intriligator, ed., ''Handbook of Mathematical Economics'', v. 1, pp. 285–330 {{DOI|10.1016/S1573-4382(81)01011-4}}.<br /> • [[Carl Shapiro]] (1989). "The Theory of Business Strategy," ''RAND Journal of Economics'', 20(1), pp. 125–37 {{JSTOR|2555656}}.</ref> | |||
<ref name=r2>• [[Leigh Tesfatsion]] (2006). "Agent-Based Computational Economics: A Constructive Approach to Economic Theory," ch. 16, ''Handbook of Computational Economics'', v. 2, pp. 831–80 {{DOI|10.1016/S1574-0021(05)02016-2}}.<br /> • [[Joseph Y. Halpern]] (2008). "computer science and game theory," ''The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics'', 2nd Edition. [http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_C000566&edition=current&q=&topicid=&result_number=1 Abstract].</ref> | |||
<ref name=r3>• From ''[[The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics]]'' (2008), 2nd Edition:<br /> [[Roger B. Myerson]]. "mechanism design." [http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_M000132&edition=current&q=mechanism%20design&topicid=&result_number=3 Abstract] {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20111123042038/http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_M000132&edition=current&q=mechanism%20design&topicid=&result_number=3 |date=November 23, 2011 }}.<br /> _____. "revelation principle." [http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_R000137&edition=current&q=moral&topicid=&result_number=1 Abstract].<br /> • Tuomas Sandholm. "computing in mechanism design." [http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_C000563&edition=&field=keyword&q=algorithmic%20mechanism%20design&topicid=&result_number=1 Abstract.] {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20111123042038/http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_C000563&edition=&field=keyword&q=algorithmic%20mechanism%20design&topicid=&result_number=1 |date=November 23, 2011 }}<br /> • [[Noam Nisan]] and Amir Ronen (2001). "Algorithmic Mechanism Design," ''Games and Economic Behavior'', 35(1–2), pp. [https://www.cs.cmu.edu/~sandholm/cs15-892F09/Algorithmic%20mechanism%20design.pdf 166–96].<br /> • [[Noam Nisan]] ''et al''., ed. (2007). ''Algorithmic Game Theory'', Cambridge University Press. [http://www.cup.cam.ac.uk/asia/catalogue/catalogue.asp?isbn=9780521872829 Description] {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120505140924/http://www.cup.cam.ac.uk/asia/catalogue/catalogue.asp?isbn=9780521872829 |date=2012-05-05 }}.</ref> | |||
<ref name=r4>Aumann, R. and Hart, S. (eds.) (1994). ''Handbook of Game Theory with Economic Applications'', v. 2, ch. 30: [http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S1574000505800621 "Voting Procedures"] and ch. 31: [http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S1574000505800633 "Social Choice."]</ref> | |||
<ref name=r5>• [[Vernon L. Smith]], 1992. "Game Theory and Experimental Economics: Beginnings and Early Influences," in E. R. Weintraub, ed., ''Towards a History of Game Theory'', pp. [https://books.google.com/books?hl=en&lr=&id=9CHY2Gozh1MC&oi=fnd&pg=PA241 241–82].<br /> • _____, 2001. "Experimental Economics," ''[[International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences]]'', pp. 5100–08. [http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/B0080430767022324 Abstract] per sect. 1.1 & 2.1.<br /> • [[Charles R. Plott]] and Vernon L. Smith, ed., 2008. ''Handbook of Experimental Economics Results'', v. 1, Elsevier, Part 4, Games, [http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/handbooks/15740722 ch. 45–66].<br /> • Vincent P. Crawford (1997). "Theory and Experiment in the Analysis of Strategic Interaction," in ''Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Theory and Applications'', pp. [http://weber.ucsd.edu/~vcrawfor/CrawfordThExp97.pdf 206–42]. Cambridge. Reprinted in Colin F. Camerer ''et al''., ed. (2003). ''Advances in Behavioral Economics'', Princeton. 1986–2003 papers. [http://press.princeton.edu/titles/8437.html Description], [https://books.google.com/books?id=sA4jJOjwCW4C&printsec=find&pg=PR7 preview], Princeton, ch. 12.<br /> • Martin Shubik, 2002. "Game Theory and Experimental Gaming," in R. Aumann and S. Hart, ed., ''Handbook of Game Theory with Economic Applications'', Elsevier, v. 3, pp. 2327–51. {{DOI|10.1016/S1574-0005(02)03025-4}}.</ref> | |||
<ref name=r6>From ''The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics'' (2008), 2nd Edition: <br /> • [[Faruk Gul]]. "behavioural economics and game theory." [http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_G000210&q=Behavioral%20economics%20&topicid=&result_number=2 Abstract.]<br /> • [[Colin F. Camerer]]. "behavioral game theory." [http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_B000302&q=Behavioral%20economics%20&topicid=&result_number=13 Abstract.] {{webarchive |url=https://web.archive.org/web/20111123034346/http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_B000302&q=Behavioral%20economics%20&topicid=&result_number=13 |date=November 23, 2011 }}<br /> • _____ (1997). "Progress in Behavioral Game Theory," ''Journal of Economic Perspectives'', 11(4), p. 172, pp. [http://authors.library.caltech.edu/22122/1/2138470%5B1%5D.pdf 167–88].<br /> • _____ (2003). ''Behavioral Game Theory'', Princeton. [http://press.princeton.edu/chapters/i7517.html Description], [https://books.google.com/books?id=cr_Xg7cRvdcC&printsec=find&pg=PR7 preview] ([ctrl]+), and ch. 1 [http://press.princeton.edu/chapters/i7517.pdf link].<br /> • _____, [[George Loewenstein]], and [[Matthew Rabin]], ed. (2003). ''Advances in Behavioral Economics'', Princeton. 1986–2003 papers. [http://press.princeton.edu/titles/8437.html Description], [https://books.google.com/books?id=sA4jJOjwCW4C&printsec=find&pg=PR7 contents], and [https://books.google.com/books?id=sA4jJOjwCW4C&printsec=find&pg=PR7 preview].<br /> • [[Drew Fudenberg]] (2006). "Advancing Beyond ''Advances in Behavioral Economics''," ''Journal of Economic Literature'', 44(3), pp. 694–711 {{JSTOR|30032349}}.</ref> | |||
== | <ref name=r7>• Eric Rasmusen (2007). ''Games and Information'', 4th ed. [http://www.wiley.com/WileyCDA/WileyTitle/productCd-EHEP001009.html Description] and [https://books.google.com/books?id=5XEMuJwnBmUC&printsec=fnd&pg=PR5 chapter-preview.]<br /> • [[David M. Kreps]] (1990). ''Game Theory and Economic Modelling''. [http://econpapers.repec.org/bookchap/oxpobooks/9780198283812.htm Description.]<br /> • R. Aumann and S. Hart, ed. (1992, 2002). ''Handbook of Game Theory with Economic Applications'' v. 1, [http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/handbooks/15740005/1 ch. 3–6] and v. 3, [http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S1574000502030060 ch. 43].</ref> | ||
The | <ref name=r8>• [[Jean Tirole]] (1988). ''The Theory of Industrial Organization'', MIT Press. [https://books.google.com/books?id=HIjsF0XONF8C&source=gbs_navlinks_s Description] and chapter-preview links, pp. [https://books.google.com/books?id=HIjsF0XONF8C&printsec=find&pg=PR7 vii–ix], "General Organization," pp. [https://books.google.com/books?id=HIjsF0XONF8C&dq=find&pg=PA5 5–6], and "Non-Cooperative Game Theory: A User's Guide Manual,' " ch. 11, pp. [https://books.google.com/books?id=HIjsF0XONF8C&dq=find&pg=PA423 423–59].<br /> • Kyle Bagwell and Asher Wolinsky (2002). "Game theory and Industrial Organization," ch. 49, ''Handbook of Game Theory with Economic Applications'', | ||
v. 3, pp. [http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S1574000502030126 1851–1895].<br /> • Martin Shubik (1959). ''Strategy and Market Structure: Competition, Oligopoly, and the Theory of Games'', Wiley. [http://devirevues.demo.inist.fr/handle/2042/29380 Description] and review [https://www.jstor.org/pss/40434883 extract].<br /> • _____ with Richard Levitan (1980). ''Market Structure and Behavior'', Harvard University Press. Review [https://www.jstor.org/pss/2232276 extract]. {{webarchive |url=https://web.archive.org/web/20100315131945/http://mitpress.mit.edu/catalog/item/default.asp?ttype=2&tid=8224 |date=15 March 2010 }}</ref> | |||
== | <ref name=r9>• Martin Shubik (1981). "Game Theory Models and Methods in Political Economy," in ''Handbook of Mathematical Economics'', v. 1, pp. 285–330 {{DOI|10.1016/S1573-4382(81)01011-4}}.<br /> •_____ (1987). ''A Game-Theoretic Approach to Political Economy''. MIT Press. [http://mitpress.mit.edu/catalog/item/default.asp?tid=5086&ttype=2 Description]. {{webarchive |url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110629151809/http://mitpress.mit.edu/catalog/item/default.asp?tid=5086&ttype=2 |date=29 June 2011 }}</ref> | ||
<ref name=r10>• Martin Shubik (1978). "Game Theory: Economic Applications," in W. Kruskal and J.M. Tanur, ed., ''International Encyclopedia of Statistics'', v. 2, pp. 372–78.<br /> • Robert Aumann and [[Sergiu Hart]], ed. ''Handbook of Game Theory with Economic Applications'' (scrollable to chapter-outline or abstract links): | |||
:1992. [http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/handbooks/15740005/1 v. 1]; 1994. [http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/handbooks/15740005/2 v. 2]; 2002. [http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/handbooks/15740005/3 v. 3.]</ref> | |||
<ref name="GT-A-E-00">N. Agarwal and P. Zeephongsekul. [http://www.mssanz.org.au/modsim2011/D6/agarwal.pdf Psychological Pricing in Mergers & Acquisitions using Game Theory], School of Mathematics and Geospatial Sciences, RMIT University, Melbourne</ref> | |||
< | }} | ||
</ | |||
{{Authority control}} | |||
{{ | |||
[[Category: | [[Category:Competition| ]] | ||
[[Category: | [[Category:Social events]] |